home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
- --------
- No. 92-1402
- --------
- C & A CARBONE, INC., et al., PETITIONERS v.
- TOWN OF CLARKSTOWN, NEW YORK
- on writ of certiorari to the appellate division,
- supreme court of new york, second judicial dept.
- [May 16, 1994]
-
- Justice Souter, with whom The Chief Justice and
- Justice Blackmun join, dissenting.
- The majority may invoke -well-settled principles of our
- Commerce Clause jurisprudence,- ante, at 1, but it does
- so to strike down an ordinance unlike anything this
- Court has ever invalidated. Previous cases have held
- that the -negative- or -dormant- aspect of the Commerce
- Clause renders state or local legislation unconstitutional
- when it discriminates against out-of-state or out-of-town
- businesses such as those that pasteurize milk, hull
- shrimp, or mill lumber, and the majority relies on these
- cases because of what they have in common with this
- one: out-of-state processors are excluded from the local
- market (here, from the market for trash processing
- services). What the majority ignores, however, are the
- differences between our local processing cases and this
- one: the exclusion worked by Clarkstown's Local Law 9
- bestows no benefit on a class of local private actors, but
- instead directly aids the government in satisfying a
- traditional governmental responsibility. The law does
- not differentiate between all local and all out-of-town
- providers of a service, but instead between the one
- entity responsible for ensuring that the job gets done
- and all other enterprises, regardless of their location.
- The ordinance thus falls outside that class of tariff or
- protectionist measures that the Commerce Clause has
- traditionally been thought to bar States from enacting
- against each other, and when the majority subsumes the
- ordinance within the class of laws this Court has struck
- down as facially discriminatory (and so avails itself of
- our -virtually per se rule- against such statutes, see
- Philadelphia v. New Jersey, 437 U. S. 617, 624 (1978)),
- the majority is in fact greatly extending the Clause's
- dormant reach.
- There are, however, good and sufficient reasons
- against expanding the Commerce Clause's inherent
- capacity to trump exercises of state authority such as
- the ordinance at issue here. There is no indication in
- the record that any out-of-state trash processor has been
- harmed, or that the interstate movement or disposition
- of trash will be affected one whit. To the degree Local
- Law 9 affects the market for trash processing services,
- it does so only by subjecting Clarkstown residents and
- businesses to burdens far different from the burdens of
- local favoritism that dormant Commerce Clause jurispru-
- dence seeks to root out. The town has found a way to
- finance a public improvement, not by transferring its
- cost to out-of-state economic interests, but by spreading
- it among the local generators of trash, an equitable
- result with tendencies that should not disturb the
- Commerce Clause and should not be disturbed by us.
-
- I
- Prior to the 1970's, getting rid of the trash in
- Clarkstown was just a matter of taking it to the local
- dump. But over the course of that decade, state
- regulators cited the town for dumping in violation of
- environmental laws, and in August 1989 the town
- entered into a consent decree with the New York State
- Department of Environmental Conservation, promising
- to close the landfill, clean up the environmental damage,
- and make new arrangements to dispose of the town's
- solid waste. Clarkstown agreed to build a -transfer
- station- where the town's trash would be brought for
- sorting out recyclable material and baling the
- nonrecyclable residue for loading into long-haul trucks
- bound for out-of-state disposal sites.
- Instead of building the transfer station itself,
- Clarkstown contracted with a private company to build
- the station and run it for five years, after which the
- town could buy it for $1. The town based the size of
- the facility on its best estimate of the amount of trash
- local residents would generate and undertook to deliver
- that amount to the transfer station each year, or to pay
- a substantial penalty to compensate for any shortfall.
- This -put or pay- contract, together with the right to
- charge an $81 -tipping- fee for each ton of waste
- collected at the transfer station, was meant to assure
- the company its return on investment.
- Local Law 9, the ordinance at issue here, is an
- integral part of this financing scheme. It prohibits
- individual trash-generators within the town from evading
- payment of the $81 tipping fee by requiring that all
- residential, commercial, and industrial waste generated
- or collected within the town be delivered to the transfer
- station. While Clarkstown residents may dump their
- waste at another locally licensed recycling center, once
- such a private recycler culls out the recyclable materials,
- it must dispose of any residue the same way other
- Clarkstown residents do, by taking it to the town's
- transfer station. Local Law 9, 3C, 3D (1990). If out-
- of-towners wish to dispose of their waste in Clarkstown
- or recycle it there, they enter the town subject to the
- same restrictions as Clarkstown residents, in being
- required to use only the town-operated transfer station
- or a licensed recycling center. 5A.
- Petitioner C & A Carbone, Inc., operated a recycling
- center in Clarkstown, according to a state permit autho-
- rizing it to collect waste, separate out the recyclables for
- sale, and dispose of the rest. In violation of Local Law
- 9, Carbone failed to bring this nonrecyclable residue to
- the town transfer station, but took it directly to out-of-
- state incinerators and landfills, including some of the
- very same ones to which the Clarkstown transfer station
- sends its trash. Apparently, Carbone bypassed the
- Clarkstown facility on account of the $81 tipping fee,
- saving Carbone money, but costing the town thousands
- in lost revenue daily. In this resulting legal action,
- Carbone's complaint is one that any Clarkstown trash
- generator could have made: the town has created a
- monopoly on trash processing services, and residents are
- no longer free to provide these services for themselves
- or to contract for them with others at a mutually agree-
- able price.
-
- II
- We are not called upon to judge the ultimate wisdom
- of creating this local monopoly, but we are asked to say
- whether Clarkstown's monopoly violates the Commerce
- Clause, as long read by this Court to limit the power of
- state and local governments to discriminate against
- interstate commerce:
- -[The] `negative' aspect of the Commerce Clause
- prohibits economic protectionism-that is, regulatory
- measures designed to benefit in-state economic in-
- terests by burdening out-of-state competitors. Thus,
- state statutes that clearly discriminate against
- interstate commerce are routinely struck down,
- unless the discrimination is demonstrably justified
- by a valid factor unrelated to economic protection-
- ism.- New Energy Co. of Indiana v. Limbach, 486
- U. S. 269, 273-274 (1988) (citations omitted).
- This limitation on the state and local power has been
- seen implicit in the Commerce Clause because, as the
- majority recognizes, the Framers sought to dampen
- regional jealousies in general and, in particular, to
- eliminate retaliatory tariffs, which had poisoned com-
- mercial relations under the Articles of Confederation.
- Ante, at 5. Laws that hoard for local businesses the
- right to serve local markets or develop local resources
- work to isolate States from each other and to incite
- retaliation, since no State would stand by while another
- advanced the economic interests of its own business
- classes at the expense of its neighbors.
-
- A
- The majority argues that resolution of the issue before
- us is controlled by a line of cases in which we have
- struck down state or local laws that discriminate
- against out-of state or out-of-town providers of process-
- ing services. See ante, at 6-7. With perhaps one ex-
- ception, the laws invalidated in those cases were pa-
- tently discriminatory, differentiating by their very terms
- between in-state and out-of-state (or local and nonlocal)
- processors. One ordinance, for example, forbad selling
- pasteurized milk -`unless the same shall have been pas-
- teurized and bottled . . . within a radius of five miles
- from the central portion of the City of Madison . . . .'-
- Dean Milk Co. v. Madison, 340 U. S. 349, 350, n. 1
- (1951) (quoting General Ordinances of the City of Madi-
- son 7.21 (1949)). The other laws expressly discriminat-
- ed against commerce crossing state lines, placing these
- local processing cases squarely within the larger class of
- cases in which this Court has invalidated facially dis-
- criminatory legislation.
- As the majority recognizes, Local Law 9 shares two
- features with these local processing cases. It regulates
- a processing service available in interstate commerce,
- i.e., the sorting and baling of solid waste for disposal.
- And it does so in a fashion that excludes out-of-town
- trash processors by its very terms. These parallels
- between Local Law 9 and the statutes previously invali-
- dated confer initial plausibility on the majority's classifi-
- cation of this case with those earlier ones on processing,
- and they even bring this one within the most general
- language of some of the earlier cases, abhorring the
- tendency of such statutes -to impose an artificial rigidi-
- ty on the economic pattern of the industry,- Toomer v.
- Witsell, 334 U. S. 385, 404-405 (1948).
-
- B
- There are, however, both analytical and practical
- differences between this and the earlier processing
- cases, differences the majority underestimates or over-
- looks but which, if given their due, should prevent this
- case from being decided the same way. First, the terms
- of Clarkstown's ordinance favor a single processor, not
- the class of all such businesses located in Clarkstown.
- Second, the one proprietor so favored is essentially an
- agent of the municipal government, which (unlike
- Carbone or other private trash processors) must ensure
- the removal of waste according to acceptable standards
- of public health. Any discrimination worked by Local
- Law 9 thus fails to produce the sort of entrepreneurial
- favoritism we have previously defined and condemned as
- protectionist.
-
- 1
- The outstanding feature of the statutes reviewed in
- the local processing cases is their distinction between
- two classes of private economic actors according to
- location, favoring shrimp hullers within Louisiana, milk
- pasteurizers within five miles of the center of Madison,
- and so on. See Foster-Fountain Packing Co. v. Haydel,
- 278 U. S. 1 (1928); Dean Milk Co. v. Madison, supra.
- Since nothing in these local processing laws prevented
- a proliferation of local businesses within the State or
- town, the out-of-town processors were not excluded as
- part and parcel of a general exclusion of private firms
- from the market, but as a result of discrimination
- among such firms according to geography alone. It was
- because of that discrimination in favor of local business-
- es, preferred at the expense of their out-of-town or out-
- of-state competitors, that the Court struck down those
- local processing laws as classic examples of the eco-
- nomic protectionism the dormant Commerce Clause
- jurisprudence aims to prevent. In the words of one
- commentator summarizing our case law, it is laws
- -adopted for the purpose of improving the competitive
- position of local economic actors, just because they are
- local, vis---vis their foreign competitors- that offend the
- Commerce Clause. Regan, The Supreme Court and
- State Protectionism: Making Sense of the Dormant
- Commerce Clause, 84 Mich. L. Rev. 1091, 1138 (1986).
- The Commerce Clause does not otherwise protect access
- to local markets. Id., at 1128.
- The majority recognizes, but discounts, this difference
- between laws favoring all local actors and this law
- favoring a single municipal one. According to the ma-
- jority, -this difference just makes the protectionist effect
- of the ordinance more acute- because outside investors
- cannot even build competing facilities within
- Clarkstown. Ante, at 8. But of course Clarkstown
- investors face the same prohibition, which is to say that
- Local Law 9's exclusion of outside capital is part of a
- broader exclusion of private capital, not a discrimination
- against out-of-state investors as such. Cf. Lewis v. BT
- Investment Managers, Inc., 447 U. S. 27 (1980) (striking
- down statute prohibiting businesses owned by out-of-
- state banks, bank holding companies, or trust companies
- from providing investment advisory services). Thus,
- while these differences may underscore the ordinance's
- anticompetitive effect, they substantially mitigate any
- protectionist effect, for subjecting out-of-town investors
- and facilities to the same constraints as local ones is
- not economic protectionism. See New Energy Co. of
- Indiana v. Limbach, 486 U. S., at 273-274.
-
- 2
- Nor is the monopolist created by Local Law 9 just
- another private company successfully enlisting local
- government to protect the jobs and profits of local citi-
- zens. While our previous local processing cases have
- barred discrimination in markets served by private
- companies, Clarkstown's transfer station is essentially a
- municipal facility, built and operated under a contract
- with the municipality and soon to revert entirely to
- municipal ownership. This, of course, is no mere coin-
- cidence, since the facility performs a municipal function
- that tradition as well as state and federal law recognize
- as the domain of local government. Throughout the
- history of this country, municipalities have taken re-
- sponsibility for disposing of local garbage to prevent
- noisome smells, obstruction of the streets, and threats
- to public health, and today 78 percent of landfills
- receiving municipal solid waste are owned by local
- governments. See U. S. Environmental Protection Agen-
- cy, Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, Subtitle D
- Study: Phase 1 Report, table 4-2, p. 4-7 (Oct. 1986).
- The National Government provides -technical and finan-
- cial assistance to States or regional authorities for
- comprehensive planning- with regard to the disposal of
- solid waste, 42 U. S. C. 6941, and the State of New
- York authorizes local governments to prepare such
- management plans for the proper disposal of all solid
- waste generated within their jurisdictions, N. Y. Envir.
- Conserv. Law 27-0107 (McKinney Supp. 1994). These
- general provisions underlie Clarkstown's more specific
- obligation (under its consent decree with the New York
- State Department of Environmental Conservation) to
- establish a transfer station in place of the old town
- dump, and it is to finance this transfer station that
- Local Law 9 was passed.
- The majority ignores this distinction between public
- and private enterprise, equating Local Law 9's
- -hoard[ing]- of solid waste for the municipal transfer
- station with the design and effect of ordinances that
- restrict access to local markets for the benefit of local
- private firms. Ante, at 7. But private businesses,
- whether local or out of State, first serve the private
- interests of their owners, and there is therefore only
- rarely a reason other than economic protectionism for
- favoring local businesses over their out-of-town competi-
- tors. The local government itself occupies a very differ-
- ent market position, however, being the one entity that
- enters the market to serve the public interest of local
- citizens quite apart from private interest in private
- gain. Reasons other than economic protectionism are
- accordingly more likely to explain the design and effect
- of an ordinance that favors a public facility. The facili-
- ty as constructed might, for example, be one that pri-
- vate economic actors, left to their own devices, would
- not have built, but which the locality needs in order to
- abate (or guarantee against creating) a public nuisance.
- There is some evidence in this case that this is so, as
- the New York State Department of Environmental
- Conservation would have had no reason to insist that
- Clarkstown build its own transfer station if the private
- market had furnished adequate processing capacity to
- meet Clarkstown's needs. An ordinance that favors a
- municipal facility, in any event, is one that favors the
- public sector, and if -we continue to recognize that the
- States occupy a special and specific position in our
- constitutional system and that the scope of Congress'
- authority under the Commerce Clause must reflect that
- position,- Garcia v. San Antonio Metropolitan Transit
- Authority, 469 U. S. 528, 556 (1985), then surely this
- Court's dormant Commerce Clause jurisprudence must
- itself see that favoring state-sponsored facilities differs
- from discriminating among private economic actors, and
- is much less likely to be protectionist.
-
- 3
- Having established that Local Law 9 does not serve
- the competitive class identified in previous local process-
- ing cases and that Clarkstown differs correspondingly
- from other local processors, we must ask whether these
- differences justify a standard of dormant Commerce
- Clause review that differs from the virtually fatal scru-
- tiny imposed in those earlier cases. I believe they do.
- The justification for subjecting the local processing
- laws and the broader class of clearly discriminatory
- commercial regulation to near-fatal scrutiny is the virtu-
- al certainty that such laws, at least in their discrimina-
- tory aspect, serve no legitimate, nonprotectionist pur-
- pose. See Philadelphia v. New Jersey, 437 U. S. 617,
- 624 (1978) (-[W]here simple economic protectionism is
- effected by state legislation, a virtually per se rule of
- invalidity has been erected-). Whether we find the
- -the evil of protectionism,- id., at 626, in the clear
- import of specific statutory provisions or in the legisla-
- ture's ultimate purpose, the discriminatory scheme is
- almost always designed either to favor local industry, as
- such, or to achieve some other goal while exporting a
- disproportionate share of the burden of attaining it,
- which is merely a subtler form of local favoritism. Id.,
- at 626-628.
- On the other hand, in a market served by a municipal
- facility, a law that favors that single facility over all
- others is a law that favors the public sector over all
- private-sector processors, whether local or out of State.
- Because the favor does not go to local private competi-
- tors of out-of-state firms, out-of-state governments will
- at the least lack a motive to favor their own firms in
- order to equalize the positions of private competitors.
- While a preference in favor of the government may
- incidentally function as local favoritism as well, a more
- particularized enquiry is necessary before a court can
- say whether such a law does in fact smack too strongly
- of economic protectionism. If Local Law 9 is to be
- struck down, in other words, it must be under that test
- most readily identified with Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc.,
- 397 U. S. 137 (1970).
-
- III
- We have said that when legislation that does not
- facially discriminate -comes into conflict with the Com-
- merce Clause's overriding requirement of a national
- `common market,' we are confronted with the task of
- effecting an accommodation of the competing national
- and local interests.- Hunt v. Washington State Apple
- Advertising Comm'n, 432 U. S. 333, 350 (1977). Al-
- though this analysis of competing interests has some-
- times been called a -balancing test,- it is not so much
- an open-ended weighing of an ordinance's pros and cons,
- as an assessment of whether an ordinance discriminates
- in practice or otherwise unjustifiably operates to isolate
- a State's economy from the national common market. If
- a statute or local ordinance serves a legitimate local
- interest and does not patently discriminate, -it will be
- upheld unless the burden imposed on [interstate] com-
- merce is clearly excessive in relation to the putative
- local benefits.- Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., supra, at
- 142. The analysis is similar to, but softer around the
- edges than, the test we employ in cases of overt dis-
- crimination. -[T]he question becomes one of degree,-
- and its answer depends on the nature of the burden on
- interstate commerce, the nature of the local interest,
- and the availability of alternative methods for advancing
- the local interest without hindering the national one.
- Id., at 142, 145.
- The primary burden Carbone attributes to flow control
- ordinances such as Local Law 9 is that they -prevent
- trash from being sent to the most cost-effective disposal
- facilities, and insulate the designated facility from all
- price competition.- Brief for Petitioner 32. In this case,
- customers must pay $11 per ton more for dumping
- trash at the Clarkstown transfer station than they
- would pay at Carbone's facility, although this dollar
- figure presumably overstates the burden by disguising
- some differences between the two: according to its state
- permit, 90 percent of Carbone's waste stream comprises
- recyclable cardboard, while the Clarkstown facility takes
- all manner of less valuable waste, which it treats with
- state-of-the-art environmental technology not employed
- at Carbone's more rudimentary plant.
- Fortunately, the dollar cost of the burden need not be
- pinpointed, its nature being more significant than its
- economic extent. When we look to its nature, it should
- be clear that the monopolistic character of Local Law 9's
- effects is not itself suspicious for purposes of the Com-
- merce Clause. Although the right to compete is a hall-
- mark of the American economy and local monopolies are
- subject to challenge under the century-old Sherman
- Act, the bar to monopolies (or, rather, the authority
- to dismember and penalize them) arises from a statuto-
- ry, not a constitutional, mandate. No more than the
- Fourteenth Amendment, the Commerce Clause -does not
- enact Mr. Herbert Spencer's Social Statics . . . [or]
- embody a particular economic theory, whether of pater-
- nalism . . . or of laissez faire.- Lochner v. New York,
- 198 U. S. 45, 75 (1905) (Holmes, J., dissenting). The
- dormant Commerce Clause does not -protec[t] the partic-
- ular structure or methods of operation in a[ny] . . .
- market.- Exxon Corp. v. Governor of Md., 437 U. S.
- 117, 127 (1978). The only right to compete that it
- protects is the right to compete on terms independent of
- one's location.
- While the monopolistic nature of the burden may be
- disregarded, any geographically discriminatory elements
- must be assessed with care. We have already observed
- that there is no geographically based selection among
- private firms, and it is clear from the face of the ordi-
- nance that nothing hinges on the source of trash that
- enters Clarkstown or upon the destination of the pro-
- cessed waste that leaves the transfer station. There is,
- to be sure, an incidental local economic benefit, for the
- need to process Clarkstown's trash in Clarkstown will
- create local jobs. But this local boon is mitigated by
- another feature of the ordinance, in that it finances
- whatever benefits it confers on the town from the pock-
- ets of the very citizens who passed it into law. On the
- reasonable assumption that no one can avoid producing
- some trash, every resident of Clarkstown must bear a
- portion of the burden Local Law 9 imposes to support
- the municipal monopoly, an uncharacteristic feature of
- statutes claimed to violate the Commerce Clause.
- By way of contrast, most of the local processing stat-
- utes we have previously invalidated imposed require-
- ments that made local goods more expensive as they
- headed into the national market, so that out-of-state
- economies bore the bulk of any burden. Requiring that
- Alaskan timber be milled in that State prior to export
- would add the value of the milling service to the Alas-
- kan economy at the expense of some other State, but
- would not burden the Alaskans who adopted such a law.
- Cf. South-Central Timber Development, Inc. v. Wunnicke,
- 467 U. S. 82, 92 (1984). Similarly, South Carolinians
- would retain the financial benefit of a local processing
- requirement for shrimp without paying anything more
- themselves. Cf. Toomer v. Witsell, 334 U. S., at 403.
- And in Philadelphia v. New Jersey, 437 U. S., at 628,
- the State attempted to export the burden of conserving
- its scarce landfill space by barring the importation of
- out-of-state waste. See also Brown-Forman Distillers
- Corp. v. New York State Liquor Authority, 476 U. S.
- 573, 580 (1986) (price reduction for in-state consumers
- of alcoholic beverages procured at the expense of out-of-
- state consumers). Courts step in through the dormant
- Commerce Clause to prevent such exports because legis-
- lative action imposing a burden -`principally upon those
- without the state . . . is not likely to be subjected to
- those political restraints which are normally exerted on
- legislation where it affects adversely some interests
- within the state.'- South-Central Timber, supra, at 92
- (quoting South Carolina State Highway Dept. v. Barn-
- well Brothers, Inc., 303 U. S. 177, 185, n. 2 (1938)); see
- also Southern Pacific Co. v. Arizona ex rel. Sullivan,
- 325 U. S. 761, 767-768, n. 2 (1945). Here, in contrast,
- every voter in Clarkstown pays to fund the benefits of
- flow control, however high the tipping fee is set. Since,
- indeed, the mandate to use the town facility will only
- make a difference when the tipping fee raises the cost
- of using the facility above what the market would other-
- wise set, the Clarkstown voters are funding their benefit
- by assessing themselves and paying an economic penal-
- ty. Any whiff of economic protectionism is far from
- obvious.
- An examination of the record confirms skepticism that
- enforcement of the ordinance portends a Commerce
- Clause violation, for it shows that the burden falls
- entirely on Clarkstown residents. If the record con-
- tained evidence that Clarkstown's ordinance burdened
- out-of-town providers of garbage sorting and baling
- services, rather than just the local business that is a
- party in this case, that fact might be significant. But
- petitioner has presented no evidence that there are
- transfer stations outside Clarkstown capable of handling
- the town's business, and the record is devoid of evidence
- that such enterprises have lost business as a result of
- this ordinance. Cf. Pike v. Bruce Church, Inc., 397
- U. S., at 145 (-The nature of th[e] burden is, consti-
- tutionally, more significant than its extent- and the
- danger to be avoided is that of laws that hoard business
- for local residents). Similarly, if the record supported
- an inference that above-market pricing at the
- Clarkstown transfer station caused less trash to flow to
- out-of-state landfills and incinerators, that, too, might
- have constitutional significance. There is, however, no
- evidence of any disruption in the flow of trash from
- curbsides in Clarkstown to landfills in Florida and
- Ohio. Here we can confidently say that the only
- business lost as a result of this ordinance is business
- lost in Clarkstown, as customers who had used Car-
- bone's facility drift away in response to any higher fees
- Carbone may have to institute to afford its share of city
- services; but business lost in Clarkstown as a result of
- a Clarkstown ordinance is not a burden that offends the
- Constitution.
- This skepticism that protectionism is afoot here is
- confirmed again when we examine the governmental
- interests apparently served by the local law. As men-
- tioned already, the State and its municipalities need
- prompt, sanitary trash processing, which is imperative
- whether or not the private market sees fit to serve this
- need at an affordable price and to continue doing so
- dependably into the future. The state and local govern-
- ments also have a substantial interest in the flow-con-
- trol feature to minimize the risk of financing this ser-
- vice, for while there may be an element of exaggeration
- in the statement that -[r]esource recovery facilities
- cannot be built unless they are guaranteed a supply of
- discarded material,- H. R. Rep. No. 94-1491, p. 10
- (1976), there is no question that a -put or pay- contract
- of the type Clarkstown signed will be a significant
- inducement to accept municipal responsibility to guaran-
- tee efficiency and sanitation in trash processing. Waste
- disposal with minimal environmental damage requires
- serious capital investment, id., at 34, and there are
- limits on any municipality's ability to incur debt or to
- finance facilities out of tax revenues. Protection of the
- public fisc is a legitimate local benefit directly advanced
- by the ordinance and quite unlike the generalized ad-
- vantage to local businesses that we have condemned as
- protectionist in the past. See Regan, 84 Mich. L. Rev.
- at 1120 (-raising revenue for the state treasury is a
- federally cognizable benefit-; protectionism is not); cf.
- Fort Gratiot Sanitary Landfill, Inc. v. Michigan Dept. of
- Natural Resources, 504 U. S. ___, ___ (1992) (slip op., at
- 3) (law protects private, not publicly owned, waste
- disposal capacity for domestic use); Philadelphia v. New
- Jersey, 476 U. S., at 627, n. 6 (expressing no opinion
- about State's power to favor its own residents in grant-
- ing access to state-owned resources).
- Moreover, flow control offers an additional benefit that
- could not be gained by financing through a subsidy
- derived from general tax revenues, in spreading the cost
- of the facility among all Clarkstown residents who
- generate trash. The ordinance does, of course, protect
- taxpayers, including those who already support the
- transfer station by patronizing it, from ending up with
- the tab for making provision for large-volume trash
- producers like Carbone, who would rely on the munici-
- pal facility when that was advantageous but opt out
- whenever the transfer station's price rose above the
- market price. In proportioning each resident's burden
- to the amount of trash generated, the ordinance has the
- added virtue of providing a direct and measurable deter-
- rent to the generation of unnecessary waste in the first
- place. And in any event it is far from clear that the
- alternative to flow control (i.e., subsidies from general
- tax revenues or municipal bonds) would be less disrup-
- tive of interstate commerce than flow control, since a
- subsidized competitor can effectively squelch competition
- by underbidding it.
- There is, in short, no evidence that Local Law 9 caus-
- es discrimination against out-of-town processors, because
- there is no evidence in the record that such processors
- have lost business as a result of it. Instead, we know
- only that the ordinance causes the local residents who
- adopted it to pay more for trash disposal services. But
- local burdens are not the focus of the dormant Com-
- merce Clause, and this imposition is in any event readi-
- ly justified by the ordinance's legitimate benefits in reli-
- able and sanitary trash processing.
-
- * * *
- The Commerce Clause was not passed to save the
- citizens of Clarkstown from themselves. It should not
- be wielded to prevent them from attacking their local
- garbage problems with an ordinance that does not dis-
- criminate between local and out-of-town participants in
- the private market for trash disposal services and that
- is not protectionist in its purpose or effect. Local Law
- 9 conveys a privilege on the municipal government
- alone, the only market participant that bears responsi-
- bility for ensuring that adequate trash processing servic-
- es continue to be available to Clarkstown residents.
- Because the Court's decision today is neither compelled
- by our local processing cases nor consistent with this
- Court's reason for inferring a dormant or negative as-
- pect to the Commerce Clause in the first place, I re-
- spectfully dissent.
-